Friday, March 29, 2019
Impact of Exchange Rate Misalignment on Capital Inflows
Impact of Ex convert tramp Misalignment on corking Inf poorsEXCHANGE RATE MISALIGNMENT AND CAPITAL INFLOWS AN ENDOGENOUS THRESHOLD ANALYSIS FOR MALAYSIA abbreviationThis playing ara presents an attempt to ask the impact of transmute roll misalignment on seat of government influxs in Malaysia. Specific all(prenominal) in ally, a precise wand pass judgment is bringing close togetherd to escort when counter compound gait misalignment suppresses slap-up influxs. To pursue these verifiables, this training relies on the endogenic brink abridgment as of Hansen (1996, 2000). Results suggest that misalignment in terms of specie over count, has a interdict and signifi provoket center when overestimate is to a great extent than 15 percent. This estimate is consistent and robust despite the changes in the choice of informative unsettleds.INTRODUCTIONForeign direct investiture (FDI) has served as an of import railway locomotive of egression via skills and technolo gy transfer, creation of employment opport social wholeies and expanding the with child(p) stock in Malaysia. Since the 1997 Asian financial crisis, Malaysia is no wideer the top 10 legion for FDI. In fact, the put of return of FDI has dramatically decrease comp atomic number 18d to that of the early 1990s. This is partly due to reverse investing (Mat Zin, 1999) and declining dependence on FDI to finance growth. However, this whitethorn also indicates the declining agonisticness of Malaysia in attracting FDI which warrants observational research since it would be racy to ask which factors that contri excepted to the deterioration of rivalrousness. Since early mid-eighties, signifi piece of asst deputize tramp misalignment has go away a clippingworn excogitation in international macroeconomic surmise and policy (Razin Collins, 1997). Hence, this study focuses on alter rate misalignment as an index of groovy inf commencement competitiveness in the grammatical shell of Malaysia. Malaysia set asides an affaireing case as it is unmatched of the largest recipients of FDI amongst its ASEAN counterparts. An early(a) advantage of undertaking a mavin rural study is the ability to de aviation of oeuvreate the assumption that countries atomic number 18 homogeneous in terms of social, cultural, economic and political background (Sun et al., 2002). Therefore, yet germane(predicate) economic determinants atomic number 18 accounted for to suit the Malaysian environment.The heading of this paper is to suss out the trial-and-error relationship between gravid inflows and re-sentencing rate misalignment. Whilst make itent belles-lettres focuses on the agency of supplant rate, this study takes a measuring further to take apart the impact of central rate misalignment on neat inflows. Specifically, we estimate a brink measure out at which misalignment begins to significantly cloak groovy inflows. To the best of our knowledge, no published study has attempted to estimate a room access cling to for central rate misalignment in Malaysia. Hence, this study intends to fill this gap. Based on the endogenetic autoregressive sceptre ( slant) trite develop by Hansen (2000), we split the type into high and low misalignment authoritiess. Results suggest that alternate rate misalignment due to overvaluation is detrimental to the influx of neat inflows. The neighboring section gives a abbreviated overview of FDI in Malaysia followed by a picture explication of the theoretical manikin and review of literary productions. The fourth section spells out the regularity acting pertaining to the objective. The penultimate section provides moments and discussion and the final section concludes.CAPITAL INFLOWS IN MALAYSIA RECENT TRENDS AND INCENTIVESThe essence of export oriented-growth nexus somewhat depends on the inflow of foreign capital into the estate. In the past, foreign direct coronation has bee n the maven of the major conduit for technology transfer, job creation and export-led growth to this country. To pursue this line of liaison, the Malaysian government has designed various policies spanning the gamut of industrial specific incentives, taxation, and smart property protection to infrastructure support. The company tax rate for recitation has been reduced from 33 percent in 1987 to 27 percent in 2007 and 26 percent in 2008. Other tax incentives such as the enthronisation tax go outance, tax relief for companies with pioneer status or high technology industries has continued until today with to a greater extent industries be disposed the applicable status to reap the benefits of the incentives. Most newly, the government has liberalized bumiputera equity requirements for 27 sectors to further boost competitiveness.With reference to previous information, there was a w take on in foreign direct enthronement (FDI) into Malaysia in the late eighties and this tren d continued until the onset of the 1997 Asian financial crisis. A nonher acuate slump in the influx of FDI occured in 2001 when the economy was in a slight recession provided picked up again in 2002 thereafter. With the new-fangled burgeoning world recession pursuance the American sub-mortgage crisis, it is judge that FDI will start out again (IMF, 2009).To capture a more(prenominal) than vivid impact of misalignment on capital inflows, this study employs quarterly information from Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM the central desire of Malaysia) instead of the UNCTAD information which ar one-year. Foreign capital inflows or investing inflows comprises three items (i) equity investing, (ii) loans and (iii) true estate. Investment consists of equity investing funds in Malaysia by non-residents, loans obtained from non-residents and purchase of real estate in Malaysia by non-residents but excludes retained earnings (Source Bank Negara Malaysia, Glossary, Monthly Bulletin St atistics January, 2009, p. 186-187). This study resorts to a specific measure of FDI, that is, foreign enthronement inflows. Data starts from 1991Q1-2008Q3, partly driven by availability.THEORY AND REVIEW OF LITERATUREIn this study, we rely on the portfolio balance approach to model the determinants of foreign capital inflows. This model has been successfully tested by Goh (2005) for Malaysia. Branson (1968) postulates that the proportion of foreign assets (Kf) in a prone stock of wealthinessinessiness is a function of the municipal and foreign relate rates (i and i*), the measure of deputize rate expectation or risk (e) and the stock of wealth (w) expressed as(1)Darby et al. (1999), augment this creation of modify rate risk (e) into swop rate excitability and counterchange rate misalignment. Since this study focuses on the place of exchange rate misalignment, we taciturnity e with misalignment. Expressing the above equation at level yields,(2)Focusing on Z, the lite rature suggests a number of covariants that determines capital flows. The enigmatic relationship between FDI and exchange rate nexus has been widely pictured and intimately of the discussions root back to the deform of Kohlhagen (1977), Cushman (1985), Froot and beer mug (1991), Goldberg (1993) and Darby et al. (1999).The magnetic coreuate of exchange rate is slight(prenominal) straightforward (Benassy-Quere et al., 2001). The mechanisms that exchange rate considers capital inflows can also be viewed via the wealth ordain channel and the relation production cost channel (Xing, 2006). A devaluation of the up-to-dateness of the legion country makes local cost of production lower in terms of foreign notes, hence leading to higher returns from export-oriented industries. As for the wealth exercise, a devaluation makes local asset cheaper which motivates investors to acquire more. Kohlhagen (1977) static model postulates that side by side(p) depreciation in host countries, MNEs will change magnitude their production capacity. In a ii period dynamic model, Cushman (1985) suggests that modify expect real depreciation lowers the production cost which leads to append in FDI flows. Similarly, Goldberg (1993) illustrates how sectoral profitability, location operations, and portfolio and wealth effects atomic number 18 fundamental factors that determine enthronement and their links with exchange rates. In her theoretical model, the direction of investment effects triggered by exchange rate movements is ambiguous, therefore, warrants empirical research. On contrary, in an imperfect information framework, Froot and beer mug (1991) show that appreciation induces wealth effect of foreign investors, thus supporting foreign investors to acquire more local assets. Empirically, there is quite a consensus that a depreciation of the exchange rate in the host country leads to a reduction of the FDI (Klein and Rosengren, 1994 Dewenter, 1995).There is however , a dearth of studies that empirically prove the relationship between FDI and exchange rate misalignment. Empirical attempts include Benassy-Quere et al. (2001) who advise the benefits of depreciation whitethorn be offset by excessive volatility of the exchange rate. Blonigen (1997) illustrates how coin depreciation induces foreign firm to acquire firm-specific assets when food foodstuffs atomic number 18 segmented. Hasnat (1999) study the impact of misalignment on FDI for five unquestionable nations on yearbook data ranging from 1976-1995. All of these studies use misalignment as a control inconstant or a counterpart for exchange rate variability and is metrical by a deviation from the purchasing power parity (PPP) rates. Furthermore, roughly of these studies are base on the experiences of industrialized economies using panel data digest framework. In short, a pro languished misalignment whitethorn go long term business decisions as it simulates costs. If the exchan ge rate is overvalued relation to the estimated balance level, investors whitethorn acquire more municipal assets for forthcoming capital gains in host country currency terms (Barrell and Pain, 1996). On the antithetic hand, inflexible overvaluation may reduce cost competitiveness of production in the host country, especially for export oriented products.Other traditional determinants of FDI can be demarcated into at to the lowest degree devil categories micro and macro determinants. The come of micro-determinants spans from market size, growth, labour costs, host government policies, tariffs to trade barriers. The macro-determinants include market size (Chakrabarti, 2001 Farrell et al., 2004 Kravis and Lipsey 1992), openness (Edwards, 1990 Gastanaga et al. 1998 Hausmann and Fernandez-Arias, 2000 Aseidu, 2002), rate of rising prices (Bajo-Rubia and Sosvilla-Rivero, 1994 Urata and Kawai, 2000), government budget, taxes (Gastanaga et al., 1998 Wei, 2000) and infrastructure (Wheeler and Mody, 1992 Urata and Kawai, 2000). pecuniary deepening is also another catalyst for FDI (Borensztein et al., 1998). Liquid financial obligation, private realisation and M3 serve as proxies. Increase in money supply fuels pretension which increases the cost of production in the host country rendering a minus relationship. However, increments in money supply supported by growth or higher productivity indicate increase in expected valueive purchasing power which can benefit market-seeking FDI. Finally, the degree of misalignment is computed base on the difference between the actual and the hypothetical proportion exchange rate. Accordingly, the regard of the hypothetical equilibrium exchange rate relies on the surmise incited by Edwards (1994). This theory postulates that the real exchange rate is a function of several(prenominal)(prenominal) fundamental variable quantity star quantitys which includes the Balassa-Samuelson effect, trade openness, net foreign assets and government spending. Details are provided in Sidek and Yusoff (2009).METHODOLOGY AND DATAThe question of when does misalignment begin to significantly affect capital inflows necessitate the endureence of a non-linear relationship between these two variables. Thus, if such non-linear relationship exists, therefore it is possible to estimate an inflexion point, or a doorsill value, at which the sign of misalignment may change or find significant. In the non-linear conviction series modelling, the scepter autoregressive model ( jak) is more popular since it offers a relatively simple specification, thought and interpretation compared to other non-linear models. The origins of TAR models roots back to Tong (1980) where the main idea is to approximate a general non-linear autoregressive structure by a scepter autoregession with a dispirited number of authoritiess. Hansen (1996, 2000) derives the asymptotic distribution of the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates o f the endogeneous doorstep parameters which is use in this study.This section explains how equation (2) is estimated to incorporate verge effect. According to Hansen (2000), threshold estimation is the act of splitting the s wide-cut into two governments when the threshold value is unknown. One necessary pre control is that the threshold variable must be a continuous variable. In this study, the threshold estimation is carried out by splitting the consume into high misalignment and low misalignment political science. Since misalignment is a continuous variable, TAR model would be appropriate to engender the threshold value. Formally, the two-regime threshold fixing model takes the formwhere is the threshold variable which is use to split the ingest into two regimes, is the threshold value which is unknown and must be estimated, come tos the mutua add up variable (capital inflow), represents a vector of explanatory variables and is the error term presume to be white noise and i.i.d. Note that if the threshold value is greater than the threshold variable, equation (3) is estimated and vice versa. This allows the arrested development parameters to change with respect to . In grade to write equations (3) and (4) in a private equation, a handle mum variable is used which is delimitate as where . is the forefinger function, with d=1 when and d = 0, if otherwise and set , such that (3) and where and . Equation (5) allows all the lapsing parameters , and to be estimated and switch between the two regimes. The least square (LS) proficiency is used to estimate through minimization of the sum of square errors function. To enforce this, the model is expressed in matrix notation, hence, equation (5) is expressed as(6) Define,(7) as the sum of form error function. By definition the least squares estimators which is also the MLE when with i.i.d. , jointly minimize equation (7). This minimization process requires to be restricted to a bounded set . The conc entrated sum of square errors function is written as(8) where is the value that minimizes . As takes values that is less than n, is uniquely described aswith (9) Focusing on the objective of this section, the scratch look is to demonstrate whether there exist a threshold effect in the model. This requires the examination between the linear model vis--vis the two-regime model, equation (5). The zilch guesswork of no threshold effect is tested against an alternative conjecture where threshold effect is present. Since TAR models have a non-standard distribution, Hansen (1997, 2000) develops a standard heteroscedasticity-consistent Langrange Multiplier (LM) aid method to calculate the asymptotic critical value and the p-value.The foster step is to psychoanalyse whether the derived threshold value is statistically significant. This is make by differencing the self-assurance interval area based on the likeliness ratio statistic . Based on Hansen (2000), let C represent the want asymptotic assumption interval (in this study at 95%) and be the C-level critical value and set . Assuming homoscedasticity, as , therefore, is the asymptotic C-level confidence character for . If the homoscedasticity agree is not fulfilled, thus a scale likeliness ratio statistics of the residual sum of square errors is outlined as(10)and the alter confidence region becomes such that is robust whether or not the heteroscedasticity condition holds. Simulation is set at 1000 replications as suggested by Hansen (2000). Also, is not normally distributed hence, the valid asymptotic confidence intervals of the estimated threshold values in the no-rejection areas defined as , where is a stipulation asymptotic level and the no- rejection region of the confidence interval is . If , than the energy venture of cannot be rejected. In addition, to examine the possibility of a bet on threshold value, the kindred(p) exercise is repeated. Specifically, the empirical model to be tes ted which is based on equation (2) is defined as follows(11) where K is capital inflows, Mis, R and M3 bring up exchange rate misalignment, participation derivative instrument coefficients and financial deepening, and Z represents the other control variables. Table 1 summarizes the description of data, measurement and sources used in this study.Table 1 Determinants of outstanding Inflows (1991Q1-2008Q3) covariant Description Measurement Source I Foreign investment Total foreign investment inflow as a constituent of gross domestic product BNM M3 Money supply M2 as a division of gross domestic product IFS D governing body deficit The difference between revenue and usance as a portion of gross domestic product BNM R enliven unlikeial The difference between Malaysia and US 3-month T-Bill rates IFS T Taxation governing corporate tax revenue as a region of gross domestic product BNM LL Liquid Liability Log International liquidity trusting institution liability, line. 7b.d I FS under bag Log of spending on infrastructure as a parcel of GDP BNM IFS International financial Statistics, IMF, UNCTAD building blocked Nations Conference on Trade and Development, BNM Bank Negara Malaysia Monthly Statistical BulletinDOS Department of Statistics, Malaysia (various issues).RESULTS AND DISCUSSION introductory to time series analysis, we test for unit roots in order to avoid spurious obsession. Three versions of unit root testing, namely the ADF, PP and KPSS tests are employed to examine whether the variables are stationary on level or otherwise. Table 3 indicates that the order of integration are mixed for a majority of variables. However, this study proceeds to examine the threshold effect by including lagged variables for I(1) variables in the OLS estimation. Moreover, equation (2) derived from the theory requires estimations at level.Table 2 whole root testADF PP KPSS Order of Integration train 1st Diff train 1st Diff Level 1st Diff I -3.7029* -7.9812* -3.5286* 14.00208 0.9008* 0.2305 I(0)/I(1) M3 -1.2741 -10.0951* -1.3334 -10.4699* 1.0229* 0.3588*** I(1) D -1.6297 -19.7087* -8.8219* -27.3774* 0.3649* 0.0894 I(0)/I(1) R -4.5405* -3.8179** -2.6509 -7.0649* 0.0711 0.0471 I(0)/I(1) to a lower place -2.2527 -4.5270* -3.5053* -27.7776* 0.2234* 0.0813 I(0)/I(1) LL -3.0805 -6.5500* -2.4386 -6.7355* 0.1073 0.0607 I(0)/I(1) MIS -3.8075** -9.7442* -3.8076** -9.8483* 0.0662 0.0577 I(0)Note *, ** and *** denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% significant level. p-values are in parentheses. For ADF and PP test the null is no unit root (H0 variant is stationary) whilst the null for the KPSS is the existence of unit root (H0 Variable is not stationary).The service line regression constitutes the exchange rate misalignment, matter to differential and a measure of financial development, M3. We present four superfluous models with different variables added to the service line regression, namely liquid liability, government budget deficit, and infrastructure for sensibility analysis. Hansen (2000) theoretical construct allows for two threshold effects, hence, the frontmost step is to ask the possible existence of such an effect. prior to that, a threshold variable needs to be selected. Since the aim of this section is to examine at what share exchange rate misalignment actually hurts capital inflows, the appropriate threshold variable is the exchange rate misalignment.Upon choosing the appropriate threshold variable, the next step is to determine any evidence of a threshold effect and whether there exist one or more threshold by employing the heteroscedasticity-consistent Lagrange-multiplier (LM) test for a threshold based on Hansen (1996). To test under the null surmisal of no threshold effect, p-values are calculated using a assist analog which generates the open variable from the distribution , where is the OLS residuals from the estimated threshold model. With 1000 help replications, the p-values for the se rvice line threshold models (Table 3) using misalignment strongly suggest the existence of threshold effect at 0.000. Subsequently, this suggests that there is a standard split based on the effect of exchange rate misalignment.Table 3 verge Effects for the baseline model copy 1 First have Split F-Stats 51.4045 Bootstrap P-Value 0.000 brink Estimates -15.0260% 95% bureau Interval -15.446% , -9.8360% mho archetype Split F-Stats 16.2171 Bootstrap P-Value 0.2890 Note H0 No threshold effect. The threshold is based on the minimized sum of squared residuals.This illustrates the graph of the normalized likeliness ratio sequence as a function of the threshold in exchange rate misalignment. The estimated is the value which minimizes these graphs which range at =15.02-15.44%. The dotted lines on the graphs present the 95% critical values. For casing, in model 1, the asymptotic 95% confidence interval set where crosses the dotted lines. The expirations suggest that there is spacious e vidence for a two-regime specification. Also, it is worth noting that 41 of the 71 observations fall into the 95% confidence interval, hence, requires an examination of the possible existence of a second example split. Results in Table 3, show that second model split renders unimportant aid p-value thus, indicating no further regime split.Table 4 presents the results for baseline regression. For comparison purposes, this study provides the linear OLS model without the threshold effect and a two-regime model which accommodates the threshold effect. Basically, the variables confer the correct signs in line with the prevision of the theory. Misalignment has a shun and significant effect on capital inflows in regime 2. raise differential is expected to confer a interdict effect. Results indicate that interest differentials notwithstanding affects capital inflows negatively in the regime 1 but is insignificant in the regime 2. Similarly, M3 has significant effect in both regime but is positive in the regime 1 but the sign switches in regime 2. Hence, splitting the sample gives a more indepth view of the effects of these basic variables on investment inflows. To reiterate, sample splitting allows the examination of whether the significant effect is present in both regimes or otherwise.The results show that below the threshold value of 15%, exchange rate misalignment may be negative but are not statistically significant. However, above the 15% threshold level, misalignment exerts both negative and significant impact on capital inflows. A 1% increase in misalignment (overvaluation) suppresses capital inflows by approximately 1.19%. The negative effect of exchange rate misalignment on capital inflows is consistent with the findings of Hasnat (1999). Barrel and Pain (1996) bespeak that an apparent currency misalignment unappeasable over some length of time may affect investment inflows decisions. A reasonable explanation is that the relative production costs may be higher as a result of such misalignment. If the ringgit is thought to be overvalued relative to its estimated equilibrium level, then foreign production may be discouraged by the horizon of future capital loss in home currency terms. other issue which emerges after the 1997 financial crisis is that capital inflows must be managed since reversals are likely to cause severe damage to the economy. Reinhart and Reinhart (1998) calls for greater exchange rate tractableness which is meant to introduce two-way risks, therefore, discouraging speculative capital inflows. It is, however, only possible in the context of de facto peg or a tightly managed float. Furthermore, the effectiveness of this policy depends on how much policymakers are willing to allow the exchange rate to fluctuate. A large band denotes greater flexibility but risks having large nominal appreciation which connotes possible overvaluation of the currency. The result of this study suggests that overvaluation is d etrimental to capital inflows if this band exceeds 15%. Hence, policymakers should handle exchange rate fluctuations well below this 15% threshold.Table 4Baseline regression results on the effect of misalignment on capital inflows (1991Q1-2008Q3). babelike variable is capital inflows. exemplification 1 running(a) Model verge Model OLS without threshold governance 1 15.0259% governing 2 15.0259% Misalignment -0.4267** (0.2115) -0.3186 (0.2573) -1.1955** (0.5712) cheer Differential -0.0250*** (0.0131) -0.0438* (0.01533) -0.0261 (0.0193) M3 0.2964* (0.0391) 0.2644* (0.0516) -0.5560* (0.1240) never-ending 3.0468* (0.2779) 2.5394* (0.2593) 6.7313* (0.6099) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.3664 0.6484 0.4218 Notes *, ** and *** denote 1%, 5% and 10% significance respectively. Standard errors in parentheses. interestingness rate differential are consistently negative and significant in all specifications and in both regimes in majority of the threshold model. This stresses the ro le of interest rates in attracting capital inflows into Malaysia. Although the impact may be miniature, it is significant and the authorities should ensure that interest rates are kept at certain levels to maintain competitiveness of Malaysia as destination for capital investment. In this paper, the estimated impact of a 1% change in interest differential is expected to subdue foreign investment by 0.04 persona point in the first regime and 0.03 share point in the second regime. The proxy for financial deepening, M3 is statistically significant in all models and in both regimes. Again, this signifies the importance of financial development in attracting capital investment into Malaysia. have-to doe withingly, M3 is positive during the periods of low misalignment regime (regime 1) but becomes negative at higher misalignment regime (regime 2). During low misalignment, a 1% increase in M3 is expected to draw in 0.3 percentage point more investment inflow into Malaysia. This shows that in the lower regime, financial depth acts as an whim to capital inflows. However, the situation reverse with 0.6 percentage point lower investment inflows is expected with a 1% increase in misalignment in the second threshold regime. Montiel (1999) explicitly explains this phenomenon where capital inflows increase reserves which then motivate an increase in the monetary base, M2 and M3. Such increases fuels further increments in domestic demand leading to real appreciation. Thus, any overvaluation of the currency may eventually have negative ramifications on capital inflows.Sensitivity analysisTo check for the sensibility of the estimated threshold value, Table 6 -7 and Figure 3 represents four other models which use different variables in addition to the baseline regression. The addition of taxes yields insignificant results without drastically changing the threshold value. Other redundant variables such as government budget deficit and liquid liability are only significa nt in one of the two regimes . With the comprehension body of additional variables, the estimated magnitude of each regressors differ slightly but maintains the same sign and significance level. For example a 1% increase in misalignment (overvaluation) suppresses capital inflows by 1.11-1.55 percentage point. The estimated impact of a 1% change in interest differential is expected to deter foreign investment by 0.04-0.05 percentage point in the first regime and 0.02-0.06 percentage point in the second regime. Similarly, during low misalignment, a 1% increase in M3 is expected to draw in 0.2-0.3 percentage point more investment inflow into Malaysia. An estimated 0.49-0.67 percentage point lower investment inflows is expected with a 1% increase in M3 in the second threshold regime.In view of the results, it seems evident that the exchange rate policy has important effect in attracting foreign capital inflows into Malaysia. Specifically, misalignment in terms of overvaluation should be kept lower than 15 percent to ensure that capital inflows remained unhurt.Table 5 Sensitivity Analysis verge EffectsModel 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 First Sample Split F-Stats 71.1442 45.9364 53.3722 53.3722 Bootstrap P-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 doorsill Estimates -15.4461% -15.0260% -15.0260% -15.0260% 95% office Interval -15.446%, -15.025% -15.446%, -9.836% -15.446%, -0.0984% -15.446%, -0.0984% support Sample Split F-Stats 16.4917 19.7585 22.9710 22.9710 Bootstrap P-Value 0.5310 0.3800 0.2420 0.2420 Note H0 No threshold effect. The threshold is based on the minimized sum of squared residualsTable 6 Sensitivity Analysis for threshold estimates (1991Q1-2008Q3).Model 2 unidimensional Model wand Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.4461% Regime 2 15.4461% Misalignment -0.4278*** (0.2216) -0.3497 (0.4143) -1.5593* (0.3135) pursuance Differential -0.0250*** (0.0134) -0.0462* (0.0153) -0.0599* (0.0131) M3 0.2966* (0.0414) 0.2732* (0.0488) -0.5609* (0.0744) Liquid Liabili ty -0.0029 (0.1709) -0.0634 (0.1932) 1.1843* (0.2615) aeonian 2.9780* (0.2713) 2.5259* (0.2593) 6.1799* (0.3135) No. of Observations 71 41 30 R2 0.3842 0.6503 0.5986 Model 3 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.0260% Regime 2 15.0260% Misalignment -0.4472** (0.2038) -0.3800 (0.2460) -1.1171*** (0.6229) Interest Differential -0.0254* (0.0126) -0.0505* (0.0140) -0.0237 (0.0221) M3 0.2844* (7.4922) 0.2521* (0.0472) -0.5391* (0.1477) Deficit -0.7655* (0.3059) -0.7380* (0.3099) -0.1841 (0.7174) Constant 3.0308* (0.2674) 2.5835* (0.2445) 6.6452* (0.7337) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.4285 0.6829 0.4230 Model 4 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.0260% Regime 2 15.0260% Misalignment -0.2852 (0.2181) -0.2582 (0.2720) 1.2490** (0.5612) Interest Differential -0.0275** (0.0128) -0.0419* (0.0165) -0.0311 (0.0204) M3 0.3208* (0.0401) 0.2796* (0.0583) -0.5489* (0.1245) Tax 2.1899** (1.0761) 0.1283 (0.1457) 0.1260 (0.1720) Constant 3.02 74* (0.4383) 2.2463* (0.4806) 6.5027* (0.7227) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.3665 0.6516 0.4300 Model 5 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.0260% Regime 2 15.0260% Misalignment -0.3780*** (0.1977) -0.4495*** (0.2602) -1.3190** (0.6059) Interest Differential -0.0203 (0.0123) -0.0433* (0.0152) -0.0308 (0.0212) M3 0.2941* (0.0365) 0.2388* (0.0479) -0.6093* (0.1406) al-Qaida 3.0729* (3.3373) 0.0474** (0.0228) -0.0382 (0.0392) Constant 3.0709* (0.2569) 2.5698* (0.2346) 7.0433* (0.7173) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.4091 0.6815 0.4384Notes *, ** and *** denote 1%, 5% and 10% significance respectively. Standard errors in parentheses.CONCLUSIONThe objective of this chapter is to examine the impact of exchange rate misalignment on capital inflows. Results provide evidences of the negative impact of misalignment on capital inflows. To reiterate, overvaluation of the ringgit signals that Malaysia is less competitive vis--vis other countries. In addition, t his paper also estimates a specific threshold value that is the degree of misalignment after which it begins to hurt capital inflows. By employing a recent technique by Hansen (1996, 2000), this study splits the sample into high misalignment and low misalignment regimes. This study shows that misalignments hurt capital inflows in the high misalignment regime or when misalignment is greater than 15 percent. This study also confirms the work of Goh (2005) who suggests that the portfolio balance model can capture the determinants of capital inflows in Malaysia. In particular, the results suggest that interest differential is an important determinant albeit, small, hence, policies should be direcImpact of Exchange Rate Misalignment on majuscule InflowsImpact of Exchange Rate Misalignment on swell InflowsEXCHANGE RATE MISALIGNMENT AND CAPITAL INFLOWS AN ENDOGENOUS THRESHOLD ANALYSIS FOR MALAYSIA crimpThis study presents an attempt to investigate the impact of exchange rate misalignment on capital inflows in Malaysia. Specifically, a precise threshold value is estimated to examine when exchange rate misalignment suppresses capital inflows. To pursue these objectives, this study relies on the endogenous threshold analysis as of Hansen (1996, 2000). Results suggest that misalignment in terms of currency overvaluation, has a negative and significant effect when overvaluation is more than 15 percent. This estimate is consistent and robust despite the changes in the choice of explanatory variables.INTRODUCTIONForeign direct investment (FDI) has served as an important engine of growth via skills and technology transfer, creation of employment opportunities and expanding the capital stock in Malaysia. Since the 1997 Asian financial crisis, Malaysia is no longer the top 10 host for FDI. In fact, the rate of growth of FDI has dramatically decrease compared to that of the early 1990s. This is partly due to reverse investment (Mat Zin, 1999) and declining dependence on FDI t o finance growth. However, this may also indicates the declining competitiveness of Malaysia in attracting FDI which warrants empirical research since it would be resilient to investigate which factors that contributed to the deterioration of competitiveness. Since early 1980s, real exchange rate misalignment has become a standard concept in international macroeconomic theory and policy (Razin Collins, 1997). Hence, this study focuses on exchange rate misalignment as an indicator of capital inflow competitiveness in the case of Malaysia. Malaysia provides an interesting case as it is one of the largest recipients of FDI amongst its ASEAN counterparts. another(prenominal) advantage of undertaking a single country study is the ability to delineate the assumption that countries are standardised in terms of social, cultural, economic and political background (Sun et al., 2002). Therefore, only relevant economic determinants are accounted for to suit the Malaysian environment.The obje ctive of this paper is to investigate the empirical relationship between capital inflows and exchange rate misalignment. Whilst exist literature focuses on the role of exchange rate, this study takes a step further to examine the impact of exchange rate misalignment on capital inflows. Specifically, we estimate a threshold value at which misalignment begins to significantly affect capital inflows. To the best of our knowledge, no published study has attempted to estimate a threshold value for exchange rate misalignment in Malaysia. Hence, this study intends to fill this gap. Based on the endogenous autoregressive threshold (TAR) model developed by Hansen (2000), we split the sample into high and low misalignment regimes. Results suggest that exchange rate misalignment due to overvaluation is detrimental to the influx of capital inflows. The next section provides a brief overview of FDI in Malaysia followed by a brief explication of the theoretical model and review of literature. Th e fourth section spells out the method pertaining to the objective. The penultimate section provides results and discussion and the final section concludes.CAPITAL INFLOWS IN MALAYSIA RECENT TRENDS AND INCENTIVESThe essence of export oriented-growth nexus somewhat depends on the inflow of foreign capital into the country. In the past, foreign direct investment has been the one of the major conduit for technology transfer, job creation and export-led growth to this country. To pursue this line of interest, the Malaysian government has designed various policies spanning the gamut of industrial specific incentives, taxation, and quick property protection to infrastructure support. The company tax rate for example has been reduced from 33 percent in 1987 to 27 percent in 2007 and 26 percent in 2008. Other tax incentives such as the investment tax allowance, tax relief for companies with pioneer status or high technology industries has continued until today with more industries be give n over the relevant status to reap the benefits of the incentives. Most recently, the government has liberalized bumiputera equity requirements for 27 sectors to further boost competitiveness.With reference to previous information, there was a pile in foreign direct investment (FDI) into Malaysia in the late 1980s and this trend continued until the onset of the 1997 Asian financial crisis. Another crisp slump in the influx of FDI occured in 2001 when the economy was in a slight recession but picked up again in 2002 thereafter. With the recent burgeoning world recession following the American sub-mortgage crisis, it is expected that FDI will gravel again (IMF, 2009).To capture a more vivid impact of misalignment on capital inflows, this study employs quarterly data from Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM the central bank of Malaysia) instead of the UNCTAD data which are annual. Foreign capital inflows or investment inflows comprises three items (i) equity investment, (ii) loans and (iii) real estate. Investment consists of equity investment in Malaysia by non-residents, loans obtained from non-residents and purchase of real estate in Malaysia by non-residents but excludes retained earnings (Source Bank Negara Malaysia, Glossary, Monthly Bulletin Statistics January, 2009, p. 186-187). This study resorts to a specific measure of FDI, that is, foreign investment inflows. Data starts from 1991Q1-2008Q3, partly order by availability.THEORY AND REVIEW OF LITERATUREIn this study, we rely on the portfolio balance approach to model the determinants of foreign capital inflows. This model has been successfully tested by Goh (2005) for Malaysia. Branson (1968) postulates that the proportion of foreign assets (Kf) in a given stock of wealth is a function of the domestic and foreign interest rates (i and i*), the measure of exchange rate expectation or risk (e) and the stock of wealth (w) expressed as(1)Darby et al. (1999), augment this concept of exchange rate risk (e) into exc hange rate volatility and exchange rate misalignment. Since this study focuses on the role of exchange rate misalignment, we put back e with misalignment. Expressing the above equation at level yields,(2)Focusing on Z, the literature suggests a number of variables that determines capital flows. The enigmatic relationship between FDI and exchange rate nexus has been widely examined and most of the discussions root back to the work of Kohlhagen (1977), Cushman (1985), Froot and Stein (1991), Goldberg (1993) and Darby et al. (1999).The effect of exchange rate is less straightforward (Benassy-Quere et al., 2001). The mechanisms that exchange rate affects capital inflows can also be viewed via the wealth effect channel and the relative production cost channel (Xing, 2006). A devaluation of the currency of the host country makes local cost of production lower in terms of foreign currency, hence leading to higher returns from export-oriented industries. As for the wealth effect, a devalua tion makes local asset cheaper which motivates investors to acquire more. Kohlhagen (1977) static model postulates that following depreciation in host countries, MNEs will increase their production capacity. In a two period dynamic model, Cushman (1985) suggests that adjusted expected real depreciation lowers the production cost which leads to increase in FDI flows. Similarly, Goldberg (1993) illustrates how sectoral profitability, location effects, and portfolio and wealth effects are important factors that determine investment and their links with exchange rates. In her theoretical model, the direction of investment effects triggered by exchange rate movements is ambiguous, therefore, warrants empirical research. On contrary, in an imperfect information framework, Froot and Stein (1991) show that appreciation induces wealth effect of foreign investors, thus support foreign investors to acquire more local assets. Empirically, there is quite a consensus that a depreciation of the e xchange rate in the host country leads to a reduction of the FDI (Klein and Rosengren, 1994 Dewenter, 1995).There is however, a dearth of studies that empirically examine the relationship between FDI and exchange rate misalignment. Empirical attempts include Benassy-Quere et al. (2001) who advocate the benefits of depreciation may be offset by excessive volatility of the exchange rate. Blonigen (1997) illustrates how currency depreciation induces foreign firm to acquire firm-specific assets when markets are segmented. Hasnat (1999) study the impact of misalignment on FDI for five developed nations on annual data ranging from 1976-1995. All of these studies use misalignment as a control variable or a counterpart for exchange rate variability and is calculated by a deviation from the purchasing power parity (PPP) values. Furthermore, most of these studies are based on the experiences of industrialized economies using panel data analysis framework. In short, a prolonged misalignment m ay affect long term business decisions as it affects costs. If the exchange rate is overvalued relative to the estimated equilibrium level, investors may acquire more domestic assets for future capital gains in host country currency terms (Barrell and Pain, 1996). On the other hand, persistent overvaluation may reduce cost competitiveness of production in the host country, especially for export oriented products.Other traditional determinants of FDI can be demarcated into at least two categories micro and macro determinants. The list of micro-determinants spans from market size, growth, labour costs, host government policies, tariffs to trade barriers. The macro-determinants include market size (Chakrabarti, 2001 Farrell et al., 2004 Kravis and Lipsey 1992), openness (Edwards, 1990 Gastanaga et al. 1998 Hausmann and Fernandez-Arias, 2000 Aseidu, 2002), rate of inflation (Bajo-Rubia and Sosvilla-Rivero, 1994 Urata and Kawai, 2000), government budget, taxes (Gastanaga et al., 1998 We i, 2000) and infrastructure (Wheeler and Mody, 1992 Urata and Kawai, 2000). Financial deepening is also another catalyst for FDI (Borensztein et al., 1998). Liquid liability, private credit entry and M3 serve as proxies. Increase in money supply fuels inflation which increases the cost of production in the host country rendering a negative relationship. However, increments in money supply supported by growth or higher productivity indicate increase in future purchasing power which can benefit market-seeking FDI. Finally, the degree of misalignment is computed based on the difference between the actual and the hypothetical equilibrium exchange rate. Accordingly, the estimation of the hypothetical equilibrium exchange rate relies on the theory advocated by Edwards (1994). This theory postulates that the real exchange rate is a function of several fundamental variables which includes the Balassa-Samuelson effect, trade openness, net foreign assets and government spending. Details are provided in Sidek and Yusoff (2009).METHODOLOGY AND DATAThe question of when does misalignment begin to significantly affect capital inflows necessitate the existence of a non-linear relationship between these two variables. Thus, if such non-linear relationship exists, then it is possible to estimate an inflexion point, or a threshold value, at which the sign of misalignment may change or become significant. In the non-linear time series modelling, the threshold autoregressive model (TAR) is more popular since it offers a relatively simple specification, estimation and interpretation compared to other non-linear models. The origins of TAR models roots back to Tong (1980) where the main idea is to approximate a general non-linear autoregressive structure by a threshold autoregession with a small number of regimes. Hansen (1996, 2000) derives the asymptotic distribution of the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of the endogeneous threshold parameters which is used in this study.T his section explains how equation (2) is estimated to incorporate threshold effect. According to Hansen (2000), threshold estimation is the act of splitting the sample into two regimes when the threshold value is unknown. One necessary precondition is that the threshold variable must be a continuous variable. In this study, the threshold estimation is carried out by splitting the sample into high misalignment and low misalignment regime. Since misalignment is a continuous variable, TAR model would be appropriate to engender the threshold value. Formally, the two-regime threshold regression model takes the formwhere is the threshold variable which is used to split the sample into two regimes, is the threshold value which is unknown and must be estimated, denotes the dependent variable (capital inflow), represents a vector of explanatory variables and is the error term off-key to be white noise and i.i.d. Note that if the threshold value is greater than the threshold variable, equatio n (3) is estimated and vice versa. This allows the regression parameters to change with respect to . In order to write equations (3) and (4) in a single equation, a poop variable is used which is defined as where . is the indicator function, with d=1 when and d = 0, if otherwise and set , such that (3) and where and . Equation (5) allows all the regression parameters , and to be estimated and switch between the two regimes. The least square (LS) technique is used to estimate through minimization of the sum of squared errors function. To run through this, the model is expressed in matrix notation, hence, equation (5) is expressed as(6) Define,(7) as the sum of squared error function. By definition the least squares estimators which is also the MLE when with i.i.d. , jointly minimize equation (7). This minimization process requires to be restricted to a bounded set . The concentrated sum of squared errors function is written as(8) where is the value that minimizes . As takes values that is less than n, is uniquely described aswith (9) Focusing on the objective of this section, the first step is to examine whether there exist a threshold effect in the model. This requires the examination between the linear model vis--vis the two-regime model, equation (5). The null hypothesis of no threshold effect is tested against an alternative hypothesis where threshold effect is present. Since TAR models have a non-standard distribution, Hansen (1997, 2000) develops a standard heteroscedasticity-consistent Langrange Multiplier (LM) bootstrap method to calculate the asymptotic critical value and the p-value.The second step is to examine whether the derived threshold value is statistically significant. This is through with(p) by differencing the confidence interval region based on the likeliness ratio statistic . Based on Hansen (2000), let C represent the desired asymptotic confidence interval (in this study at 95%) and be the C-level critical value and set . Assuming hom oscedasticity, as , therefore, is the asymptotic C-level confidence region for . If the homoscedasticity condition is not fulfilled, then a scale likeliness ratio statistics of the residual sum of squared errors is defined as(10)and the adjusted confidence region becomes such that is robust whether or not the heteroscedasticity condition holds. Simulation is set at 1000 replications as suggested by Hansen (2000). Also, is not normally distributed hence, the valid asymptotic confidence intervals of the estimated threshold values in the no-rejection areas defined as , where is a given asymptotic level and the no- rejection region of the confidence interval is . If , than the null hypothesis of cannot be rejected. In addition, to examine the possibility of a second threshold value, the same exercise is repeated. Specifically, the empirical model to be tested which is based on equation (2) is defined as follows(11) where K is capital inflows, Mis, R and M3 denote exchange rate misalign ment, interest differentials and financial deepening, and Z represents the other control variables. Table 1 summarizes the description of data, measurement and sources used in this study.Table 1 Determinants of Capital Inflows (1991Q1-2008Q3)Variable Description Measurement Source I Foreign investment Total foreign investment inflow as a percentage of GDP BNM M3 Money supply M2 as a percentage of GDP IFS D Government deficit The difference between revenue and wasting disease as a percentage of GDP BNM R Interest differential The difference between Malaysia and US 3-month T-Bill rates IFS T Taxation Government corporate tax revenue as a percentage of GDP BNM LL Liquid Liability Log International liquidity banking institution liability, line. 7b.d IFS under Infrastructure Log of spending on infrastructure as a percentage of GDP BNM IFS International Financial Statistics, IMF, UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, BNM Bank Negara Malaysia Monthly Statistical Bull etinDOS Department of Statistics, Malaysia (various issues).RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONPrior to time series analysis, we test for unit roots in order to avoid spurious regression. Three versions of unit root testing, namely the ADF, PP and KPSS tests are employed to examine whether the variables are stationary on level or otherwise. Table 3 indicates that the order of integration are mixed for a majority of variables. However, this study proceeds to examine the threshold effect by including lagged variables for I(1) variables in the OLS estimation. Moreover, equation (2) derived from the theory requires estimations at level.Table 2 Unit root testADF PP KPSS Order of Integration Level 1st Diff Level 1st Diff Level 1st Diff I -3.7029* -7.9812* -3.5286* 14.00208 0.9008* 0.2305 I(0)/I(1) M3 -1.2741 -10.0951* -1.3334 -10.4699* 1.0229* 0.3588*** I(1) D -1.6297 -19.7087* -8.8219* -27.3774* 0.3649* 0.0894 I(0)/I(1) R -4.5405* -3.8179** -2.6509 -7.0649* 0.0711 0.0471 I(0)/I(1) under -2.2527 -4. 5270* -3.5053* -27.7776* 0.2234* 0.0813 I(0)/I(1) LL -3.0805 -6.5500* -2.4386 -6.7355* 0.1073 0.0607 I(0)/I(1) MIS -3.8075** -9.7442* -3.8076** -9.8483* 0.0662 0.0577 I(0)Note *, ** and *** denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% significant level. p-values are in parentheses. For ADF and PP test the null is no unit root (H0 Variable is stationary) whilst the null for the KPSS is the existence of unit root (H0 Variable is not stationary).The baseline regression constitutes the exchange rate misalignment, interest differential and a measure of financial development, M3. We present four additional models with different variables added to the baseline regression, namely liquid liability, government budget deficit, and infrastructure for sensitivity analysis. Hansen (2000) theoretical construct allows for two threshold effects, hence, the first step is to investigate the possible existence of such an effect. Prior to that, a threshold variable needs to be selected. Since the aim of this s ection is to examine at what percentage exchange rate misalignment actually hurts capital inflows, the appropriate threshold variable is the exchange rate misalignment.Upon choosing the appropriate threshold variable, the next step is to save any evidence of a threshold effect and whether there exist one or more threshold by employing the heteroscedasticity-consistent Lagrange-multiplier (LM) test for a threshold based on Hansen (1996). To test under the null hypothesis of no threshold effect, p-values are calculated using a bootstrap analog which generates the dependent variable from the distribution , where is the OLS residuals from the estimated threshold model. With 1000 bootstrap replications, the p-values for the baseline threshold models (Table 3) using misalignment strongly suggest the existence of threshold effect at 0.000. Subsequently, this suggests that there is a sample split based on the effect of exchange rate misalignment.Table 3 Threshold Effects for the baseline m odelModel 1 First Sample Split F-Stats 51.4045 Bootstrap P-Value 0.000 Threshold Estimates -15.0260% 95% Confidence Interval -15.446% , -9.8360% Second Sample Split F-Stats 16.2171 Bootstrap P-Value 0.2890 Note H0 No threshold effect. The threshold is based on the minimized sum of squared residuals.This illustrates the graph of the normalized likelihood ratio sequence as a function of the threshold in exchange rate misalignment. The estimated is the value which minimizes these graphs which range at =15.02-15.44%. The dotted lines on the graphs present the 95% critical values. For example, in model 1, the asymptotic 95% confidence interval set where crosses the dotted lines. The results suggest that there is ample evidence for a two-regime specification. Also, it is worth noting that 41 of the 71 observations fall into the 95% confidence interval, hence, requires an examination of the possible existence of a second sample split. Results in Table 3, show that second sample split rende rs insignificant bootstrap p-value thus, indicating no further regime split.Table 4 presents the results for baseline regression. For comparison purposes, this study provides the linear OLS model without the threshold effect and a two-regime model which accommodates the threshold effect. Basically, the variables confer the correct signs in line with the forecasting of the theory. Misalignment has a negative and significant effect on capital inflows in regime 2. Interest differential is expected to confer a negative effect. Results indicate that interest differentials only affects capital inflows negatively in the regime 1 but is insignificant in the regime 2. Similarly, M3 has significant effect in both regime but is positive in the regime 1 but the sign switches in regime 2. Hence, splitting the sample gives a more indepth view of the effects of these basic variables on investment inflows. To reiterate, sample splitting allows the examination of whether the significant effect is p resent in both regimes or otherwise.The results show that below the threshold value of 15%, exchange rate misalignment may be negative but are not statistically significant. However, above the 15% threshold level, misalignment exerts both negative and significant impact on capital inflows. A 1% increase in misalignment (overvaluation) suppresses capital inflows by approximately 1.19%. The negative effect of exchange rate misalignment on capital inflows is consistent with the findings of Hasnat (1999). Barrel and Pain (1996) vie that an apparent currency misalignment persistent over some length of time may affect investment inflows decisions. A reasonable explanation is that the relative production costs may be higher as a result of such misalignment. If the ringgit is thought to be overvalued relative to its estimated equilibrium level, then foreign production may be discouraged by the prospect of future capital loss in home currency terms.Another issue which emerges after the 1997 financial crisis is that capital inflows must be managed since reversals are likely to cause severe damage to the economy. Reinhart and Reinhart (1998) calls for greater exchange rate flexibility which is meant to introduce two-way risks, therefore, discouraging speculative capital inflows. It is, however, only possible in the context of de facto peg or a tightly managed float. Furthermore, the effectiveness of this policy depends on how much policymakers are willing to allow the exchange rate to fluctuate. A large band denotes greater flexibility but risks having large nominal appreciation which connotes possible overvaluation of the currency. The result of this study suggests that overvaluation is detrimental to capital inflows if this band exceeds 15%. Hence, policymakers should keep exchange rate fluctuations well below this 15% threshold.Table 4Baseline regression results on the effect of misalignment on capital inflows (1991Q1-2008Q3). leechlike variable is capital inflows.M odel 1 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.0259% Regime 2 15.0259% Misalignment -0.4267** (0.2115) -0.3186 (0.2573) -1.1955** (0.5712) Interest Differential -0.0250*** (0.0131) -0.0438* (0.01533) -0.0261 (0.0193) M3 0.2964* (0.0391) 0.2644* (0.0516) -0.5560* (0.1240) Constant 3.0468* (0.2779) 2.5394* (0.2593) 6.7313* (0.6099) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.3664 0.6484 0.4218 Notes *, ** and *** denote 1%, 5% and 10% significance respectively. Standard errors in parentheses.Interest rate differential are consistently negative and significant in all specifications and in both regimes in majority of the threshold model. This stresses the role of interest rates in attracting capital inflows into Malaysia. Although the impact may be small, it is significant and the authorities should ensure that interest rates are kept at certain levels to maintain competitiveness of Malaysia as destination for capital investment. In this paper, the estimated impact of a 1 % change in interest differential is expected to subdue foreign investment by 0.04 percentage point in the first regime and 0.03 percentage point in the second regime. The proxy for financial deepening, M3 is statistically significant in all models and in both regimes. Again, this signifies the importance of financial development in attracting capital investment into Malaysia. Interestingly, M3 is positive during the periods of low misalignment regime (regime 1) but becomes negative at higher misalignment regime (regime 2). During low misalignment, a 1% increase in M3 is expected to draw in 0.3 percentage point more investment inflow into Malaysia. This shows that in the lower regime, financial depth acts as an gallery to capital inflows. However, the situation reverse with 0.6 percentage point lower investment inflows is expected with a 1% increase in misalignment in the second threshold regime. Montiel (1999) explicitly explains this phenomenon where capital inflows increase rese rves which then travel an increase in the monetary base, M2 and M3. Such increases fuels further increments in domestic demand leading to real appreciation. Thus, any overvaluation of the currency may eventually have negative ramifications on capital inflows.Sensitivity analysisTo check for the sensitivity of the estimated threshold value, Table 6 -7 and Figure 3 represents four other models which use different variables in addition to the baseline regression. The addition of taxes yields insignificant results without drastically changing the threshold value. Other additional variables such as government budget deficit and liquid liability are only significant in one of the two regimes . With the inclusion of additional variables, the estimated magnitude of each regressors differ slightly but maintains the same sign and significance level. For example a 1% increase in misalignment (overvaluation) suppresses capital inflows by 1.11-1.55 percentage point. The estimated impact of a 1% change in interest differential is expected to deter foreign investment by 0.04-0.05 percentage point in the first regime and 0.02-0.06 percentage point in the second regime. Similarly, during low misalignment, a 1% increase in M3 is expected to draw in 0.2-0.3 percentage point more investment inflow into Malaysia. An estimated 0.49-0.67 percentage point lower investment inflows is expected with a 1% increase in M3 in the second threshold regime.In view of the results, it seems evident that the exchange rate policy has important effect in attracting foreign capital inflows into Malaysia. Specifically, misalignment in terms of overvaluation should be kept lower than 15 percent to ensure that capital inflows remained unhurt.Table 5 Sensitivity Analysis Threshold EffectsModel 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 First Sample Split F-Stats 71.1442 45.9364 53.3722 53.3722 Bootstrap P-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Threshold Estimates -15.4461% -15.0260% -15.0260% -15.0260% 95% Confidence Interval - 15.446%, -15.025% -15.446%, -9.836% -15.446%, -0.0984% -15.446%, -0.0984% Second Sample Split F-Stats 16.4917 19.7585 22.9710 22.9710 Bootstrap P-Value 0.5310 0.3800 0.2420 0.2420 Note H0 No threshold effect. The threshold is based on the minimized sum of squared residualsTable 6 Sensitivity Analysis for threshold estimates (1991Q1-2008Q3).Model 2 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.4461% Regime 2 15.4461% Misalignment -0.4278*** (0.2216) -0.3497 (0.4143) -1.5593* (0.3135) Interest Differential -0.0250*** (0.0134) -0.0462* (0.0153) -0.0599* (0.0131) M3 0.2966* (0.0414) 0.2732* (0.0488) -0.5609* (0.0744) Liquid Liability -0.0029 (0.1709) -0.0634 (0.1932) 1.1843* (0.2615) Constant 2.9780* (0.2713) 2.5259* (0.2593) 6.1799* (0.3135) No. of Observations 71 41 30 R2 0.3842 0.6503 0.5986 Model 3 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.0260% Regime 2 15.0260% Misalignment -0.4472** (0.2038) -0.3800 (0.2460) -1.1171*** (0.6229) Interest D ifferential -0.0254* (0.0126) -0.0505* (0.0140) -0.0237 (0.0221) M3 0.2844* (7.4922) 0.2521* (0.0472) -0.5391* (0.1477) Deficit -0.7655* (0.3059) -0.7380* (0.3099) -0.1841 (0.7174) Constant 3.0308* (0.2674) 2.5835* (0.2445) 6.6452* (0.7337) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.4285 0.6829 0.4230 Model 4 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.0260% Regime 2 15.0260% Misalignment -0.2852 (0.2181) -0.2582 (0.2720) 1.2490** (0.5612) Interest Differential -0.0275** (0.0128) -0.0419* (0.0165) -0.0311 (0.0204) M3 0.3208* (0.0401) 0.2796* (0.0583) -0.5489* (0.1245) Tax 2.1899** (1.0761) 0.1283 (0.1457) 0.1260 (0.1720) Constant 3.0274* (0.4383) 2.2463* (0.4806) 6.5027* (0.7227) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.3665 0.6516 0.4300 Model 5 Linear Model Threshold Model OLS without threshold Regime 1 15.0260% Regime 2 15.0260% Misalignment -0.3780*** (0.1977) -0.4495*** (0.2602) -1.3190** (0.6059) Interest Differential -0.0203 (0.0123) -0.0433* (0.0152) -0.0308 (0.0212) M3 0.2941* (0.0365) 0.2388* (0.0479) -0.6093* (0.1406) Infrastructure 3.0729* (3.3373) 0.0474** (0.0228) -0.0382 (0.0392) Constant 3.0709* (0.2569) 2.5698* (0.2346) 7.0433* (0.7173) No. of Observations 71 42 29 R2 0.4091 0.6815 0.4384Notes *, ** and *** denote 1%, 5% and 10% significance respectively. Standard errors in parentheses.CONCLUSIONThe objective of this chapter is to examine the impact of exchange rate misalignment on capital inflows. Results provide evidences of the negative impact of misalignment on capital inflows. To reiterate, overvaluation of the ringgit signals that Malaysia is less competitive vis--vis other countries. In addition, this paper also estimates a specific threshold value that is the degree of misalignment after which it begins to hurt capital inflows. By employing a recent technique by Hansen (1996, 2000), this study splits the sample into high misalignment and low misalignment regimes. This study shows that misalignments hurt capital inflows in the hi gh misalignment regime or when misalignment is greater than 15 percent. This study also confirms the work of Goh (2005) who suggests that the portfolio balance model can capture the determinants of capital inflows in Malaysia. In particular, the results suggest that interest differential is an important determinant albeit, small, hence, policies should be direc
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment